Many commentators either
complain that the European Central Bank has not followed the FED, the Bank of
England and the Bank of Japan on the Quantitative Easing (QE) path of purchasing
very large amounts of securities or, more kindly, advice the ECB to go that way,
to more forcefully fight the risk of too low inflation [1].
While I have not at all
excluded that the ECB may have to do more to symmetrically respect its
inflation objective [2], I have put QE on the bottom of the rank of
measures the ECB could take, together with a negative deposit rate. In a previous post [3], I have
explained the reasons for my assessment that a negative deposit rate is at the
bottom of the list. In this post I want, instead, to give the
reasons why I regard QE one of the least advisable measures for the ECB. In order to simplify and
shorten my analysis, I will carry it out on a "differential" basis.
This means that I will not consider the desirability of this course of action
on an absolute basis, but as a difference with respect to the FED situation.
This will spare me, and the reader, the effort of assessing whether the action of the FED to push down the long part of the yield curve through QE was both desirable and effective. In simpler terms, the point I address is: whatever are the merits
of QE carried out by the FED, are there differences between the American and
the €-area situation that advice the ECB not to follow the FED example?
A look at the motivation
of the FED in carrying out QE is a good starting point for the analysis.
Basically, confronted with the zero lower bound and given the assumption that a
negative interest rate would be needed to respect the dual mandate, the FED has purchased in
3 waves a huge amount of Treasuries and Mortgage Backed Securities (so far a total of around 2.4 trillion dollar). This should have lowered the yield on the
purchased bond and pushed investors towards riskier assets through a portfolio
balance effect. Huge purchases were needed given the liquidity of the Treasuries
and MBS market. At a certain point the FED estimated in 9 basis points the effect of
100 billion purchases on the yield of 10 year treasuries [4].
Compare these purchases
with the outright purchases conducted by the ECB: the two covered bond
purchase programs (60 and 16 billion respectively) and the Securities Market Program (SMP) (219 billion as of February 2012, when the programme turned inactive), for a total of 295 billion. Underlying the big quantitative difference in the purchased
amounts (those of the FED are about 7 times larger than those of
the ECB) there is a qualitative difference: ECB purchases were not targeting
a reduction of long term yields but rather tried to remedy a market
dysfunction, in the covered bond segment first and in the bonds of peripheral
countries later. Much smaller amounts were not a consequence of timidity, but rather
a sign of a different objective.
Another important
difference between the FED and the ECB is the lack in Europe of a market as
liquid and efficient as that of the Treasury (and MBS) where the ECB could carry out its purchases. Many commentators suggest that this issue
could be dealt with if the ECB would purchase a basket of bonds with weights
derived from the capital key defining the ownership of the ECB by the different
national central banks. Roughly, this would mean that the ECB should buy a
basket composed for 60% by core countries bonds and for the
complement by peripheral bonds.
The sense of such
purchases escapes me. The problem in Europe is not that yields are too high but
rather the, decreasing but still prevailing, segmentation of the market. This
segmentation produces too high yields on peripheral bonds and too low ones on
core bonds. Given that, in any given jurisdiction, no investor is normally willing to fund
a bank more cheaply than the government, the result is that bank funding, and
thus bank loans, are much more expensive in the periphery than in the core: the
spread is still of the order of 2 per cent between, say
between lending extended by Italian-Spanish banks and that offered by German
banks (based on covered bond iBoxx indices). This distortion is basically the
"monetary transmission problem" that the ECB addressed first with the
SMP and then, in a more effective way, with the Outright Monetary Transaction (OMT) program.
Chart 1: Spread between Spanish and German covered bonds
Source: Markit; Data represents covered bonds iBoxx indices |
The purchase of a huge amount of core bonds would further depress their yield and push interest rates even lower just where this is not needed. Symmetrically, buying large quantities of peripheral bonds, the ECB would basically kill the OMT: it
does not make sense to promise to buy peripheral bonds in the future, if stress returns but subject
to macroeconomic conditionality, when one would be already purchasing large amounts of peripheral bonds. The biggest loss in killing the
OMT would be conditionality. This is the biggest improvement between the SMP,
which had only a rough form of conditionality, and the OMT, which clearly
conditions purchases to a macroeconomic adjustment program and thus deals with
moral hazard problems and reinforces, on the fundamental side, the effect of the possible purchases.
Of course the ECB could
desire, consistently with its forward guidance, to lower, or at least avoid an increase, of money market rates across the €-area, but there are much more direct ways of doing
this than carrying out a European version of QE: the ECB could increase excess
liquidity, thus pushing again money market rates closer to zero, for instance
by stopping to sterilize the liquidity created by the SMP, it could further
lower the policy rate, it could offer a new very long term refinancing
operation rolling over those that are gradually maturing [5], possibly with an interest rate cap which would guarantee a very low funding cost to banks and would give teeth to its forward guidance. In addition, if the ECB would want to make its financial intermediation more directly relevant for firms, especially small and medium sized ones, it could establish a program of Asset Backed Securities purchases.
In conclusion, the situation of the ECB is very different from that of the FED and the ECB has much more targeted measures at its disposal if it wants to impart an additional easing bias to its monetary policy.
In conclusion, the situation of the ECB is very different from that of the FED and the ECB has much more targeted measures at its disposal if it wants to impart an additional easing bias to its monetary policy.
*** Research assistance was provided by Mădălina Norocea
[1] An exception is the perceptive piece by J.F.Kirkegaard in
the Peterson Institute web-site: Why the European Central Bank
Will Likely Shrink from Quantitative Easing, 15th of January, 2014
[3] Should
the European Central Bank do more and go negative?
[4]Michael E. Cahill, Stefania DAmico, Canlin Li, and John S. Sears: Duration Risk versus Local Supply Channel in Treasury Yields: Evidence from the Federal Reserve’s Asset Purchase Announcements, Federal Reserve Board, Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs, April 2013
[5] Is the price stability target of the ECB at risk? and € liquidity is getting more valuable: what can be done about it?
[4]Michael E. Cahill, Stefania DAmico, Canlin Li, and John S. Sears: Duration Risk versus Local Supply Channel in Treasury Yields: Evidence from the Federal Reserve’s Asset Purchase Announcements, Federal Reserve Board, Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs, April 2013
[5] Is the price stability target of the ECB at risk? and € liquidity is getting more valuable: what can be done about it?
No comments:
Post a Comment